www.rankinfile.co.nz/rf99_deflation.html


Published, abridged, in the NZ Herald as "Could it be Keynesian theorists got it wrong?", 20 January 1999.


Inflation, Deflation and Monetary Policy

Keith Rankin, 19 January 1999

 

The latest inflation statistic - a fall in the Consumers Price Index (CPI) of 0.8% in the last quarter of 1998 - may be more than a fluke result. It raises the possibility that the 21st century may be more like the 19th and than the 20th century. Deflation rather than inflation may prove to be the norm. In the nineteenth century, the world went through two industrial revolutions, both during sustained periods of falling prices.

From the 1930s to the 1960s, we grew to associate deflation with the 1930s' depression, and inflation as a result of an overstretched economy. From the 1970s, we came to see inflation as an economic monster that could never be reversed (deflation), only tamed (disinflation). Confounding all historical precedent, inflation got worse as unemployment became endemic.

Yet, as 1999 begins, inflation has ceased. And it seems to have been disappeared throughout the developed world, regardless of the differences in monetary policy in different countries. Some, such as ourselves, have low growth and stable prices. Other countries, such as Australia and the United States, have high growth and stable prices.

Comparing Australia with New Zealand, there appears to be a much stronger link between high interest policies and low growth rates, than between such policies and low inflation rates.

Before considering the impact on inflation of a policy touted as a cure for inflation, it is necessary to have some idea of what patterns of inflation and deflation occur in the absence of such policies.

It is known that economies grow in a rhythmic rather than a steady fashion. One of the classic economics books of this century was a tome called Business Cycles, written in 1939 by an Austrian born Harvard University economist, Joseph Schumpeter. Schumpeter is now regarded as so important that modern growth theory is called "neo-Schumpetarian".

He identified three basic rhythms or cycles in modern economies: an inventory cycle of about 3 years, an investment cycle of just over 10 years, and a long wave cycle of about 50 years (or two generations). He explained the Great Depression of the early 1930s as having less to do with policy than with the underlying rhythms of industrial economies. The early 1980s were similarly difficult years, which saw these cycles all in a down phase.

Growth patterns in New Zealand throughout this century generally conform with Schumpeter's model. (See my "Cycles of Growth", December 1998.) In post-war New Zealand, the only years which do not fit are 1952 and 1953, when growth was about zero when it should have been over 5%. If this 20th century growth pattern continues, we will experience a short recovery in 1999 and 2000, another recession in 2001, and a period of sustained growth through until about 2008.

Schumpeter's analysis also suggests that the industrialised world faces long periods of alternating inflation and deflation, with deflation being predominant during periods of revolutionary technological change.

The experience of "stagflation" (simultaneous recession and inflation) in the 1970s and 1980s seemed to invalidate Schumpeter's approach. Policymaking came to be dominated by Keynesians who believed that inflation could be cured by either higher taxes or diminished government spending, and by monetarists who wanted to use high interest rates to tame what would otherwise [in their view] be rampant inflation.

Both Keynesians and monetarists lost the sense of history that was central to the Schumpetarian approach. They had little knowledge of the 19th century in which inflation and deflation gave way to each other, as a part of a rhythmic process.

What if Schumpeter's model was an accurate representation of what the 20th century would have been like had the Keynesians and monetarists not taken over? The period from the mid-1970s to the late-1990s is in most respects very similar to the period from the 1870s to the 1890s. The exception was that inflation existed in the 1980s while deflation existed in the 1880s. Could it be that the monetarists, who held the levers of power in the 1980s, inadvertently created the inflation that they were meant to be eliminating? Schumpeter's model predicted that there would be inflation to about 1974, and deflation for the remainder of this century.

In the years after 1974, world inflation rates consistently increased after restrictive monetary policies pushed up interest rates.

Cost inflation occurs when interest rates rise, because both the cost of borrowing money is high, and because shareholders expect demand dividends when fixed interest investments are an attractive alternative. Rising dividends have a similar effect on inflation as rising wages.

In the late 1980s, as world monetary policies eased, world inflation came down. New Zealand was an exception, which, following a very strong push to high interest rates in 1985, saw a resurgence of inflation.

Central banks worldwide periodically used high interest rates as an anti-inflation device in the 1990s, despite absolutely no proof that high interest rates had ever created lower inflation than would have otherwise existed. From the perspective of Schumpeter's analysis of what the 1990s should have been like, it is possible to argue that central banks' actions prevented prices from falling, whereas they thought that they were preventing prices from rising.

The mid-1990s is a good test case. New Zealand inflation had been consistently falling in the period to June 1994, and growth had been rising surprisingly quickly. Believing that growth would eventually lead to inflation, the Reserve Bank slapped the brakes on. All the statistics clearly show a rise, not a fall, in inflation for 1995-1997. In the United States, where Alan Greenspan did not apply the monetary brakes, inflation did not reappear.

Perceptions of a world economic crisis in 1998 are proving Schumpeter right [in not accepting a simple functional relationship from growth to inflation]. It looks like the developed world will experience high growth and negative inflation in 1999. The world's central banks dare not act to raise interest rates, for fear of triggering a major crash on, in particular, the American stockmarket. Hence, we may be starting to see an end-of-century world much as Schumpeter would have expected.

Inflation, in Schumpeter's model, is due for a turn upwards in the 2000s' decade. Hopefully, as growth picks up next century, our fear of inflation will have mellowed. We need to resist the temptation to grab the high interest lever whenever someone in the Reserve Bank thinks that high inflation might be just around the corner. A return early next century to inflation rates similar to those of the 1960s should be no cause for panic.

 

PS [24 January] If the 21st century does indeed follow the price level patterns of the 19th century, then we can expect inflation for most of the next two decades. Following that, we can expect a long deflation from the 2020s to the 2050s and another period of deflation in the last quarter of the 21st century. One one-off factor that may lead to inflation rather than deflation from the 2020s to the 2050s may be the ageing of the world's population, given the demands that pension funds will make on a world with depleted natural resources and an inadequate labour supply.

 


© 1999   Keith Rankin


Rankin File | 1999 titles